Two years after his death in November 2006, Nobel Prize-winning economist
Milton Friedman, a widely respected champion and philosopher of freedom,
has become an embarrassment to many former colleagues at the University
of Chicago.
More than 100 tenured faculty members have signed a letter and petition
opposing plans by the university to establish a research institute
named after the legendary free-market economist. The institute, which
would be paid for by private donations, would conduct research in economics,
medicine, public policy, and law.
Bruce Lincoln, a professor of the history of religions who helped
draft the letter and petition, declared that, “People are concerned
about the blurring of the line between Friedman’s technical work
in economics and his fairly well-known persona as a political advocate
of a very pure, free-market conservative or neoliberal position, where
the market is the solution to everything.”
The institute was proposed by the economics faculty last year and
approved by various faculty committees. Twenty-five faculty members,
researchers, and alumni from the University of Chicago have won the
Nobel Prize in economics, many of them taught by Friedman. Three Nobel
winners — Gary S. Becker, Robert E. Lucas, Jr., and James J.
Heckman — sit on the seven-member committee overseeing the institute.
Becker, an economics professor in the Graduate School of Business,
said the institute is a way the university can “compete much
more effectively against Princeton, Harvard, and Stanford — schools
much better endowed than we are.” Becker, a former student and
close friend of Friedman’s, said that if Friedman were alive
he would be proud of the institute and would take the controversy in
stride. “No one likes to be accused of things, but he was very
single-mindedly devoted to doing the best he could to get at the truth,” Becker
said. He could take controversy. He was tough."
One need not agree with all of Milton Friedman’s economic and
political views to recognize that he was one of the twentieth century’s
most important and influential advocates of freedom.
Indeed, few men and women in our time have had as much influence
in advancing free societies as did Friedman. He insisted that largely
unimpeded private competition produced better results than government
systems. “Try talking French with someone who studied in public
school,” he once said, “then with a Berlitz
graduate.” In the area of education, he was an early advocate
of vouchers to provide freedom of choice to the poor, a freedom already
possessed by the affluent.
One of his most famous arguments dealt with the causes of the Depression.
It was promoted not by changes in tariff laws or by the stock market
crash, he said, but by the Federal Reserve Board’s decision to
shrink the money supply for fear of inflation in
l929 and again in l936. Those choices choked the life out of the economy
and exacerbated a bad situation, he stated in A
Monetary History of the United States, l867-l960 (l963), which he coauthored with Anna
J. Schwartz. The book is considered the definitive history of the nation’s
money supply.
It was Milton Friedman’s belief that free enterprise was the
only form of economic organization consistent with other freedoms.
In his important book, Capitalism and Freedom, he pointed out that, “The
kind of economic organization that provides economic freedom directly,
namely, competitive capitalism, also promotes political freedom because
it separates economic power from political power and in this way enables
one to offset the other.”
He declared that, “Political freedom means the absence of coercion
of a man by his fellow men. The fundamental threat to freedom is power
to coerce, be it in the hands of a monarch, a dictator, an oligarchy,
or a monetary majority. The preservation of freedom requires the elimination
of such concentration of power to the fullest possible extent and the
dispersal and distribution of whatever power cannot be eliminated — a
system of checks and balances. By removing the organization of economic
activity from the control of political authority, the market eliminates
this source of coercive power. It enables economic strength to be a
check to political power rather than a reinforcement.”
Even those who disagreed with some of Friedman's ideas had great
respect for him and for his influence on America and the world. Laurence
Summers, a former President of Harvard and Secretary of the Treasury,
recalls that, “From what I’ve heard, Milton Friedman’s
participation on a government commission on the volunteer military
in the late l960s was a kind of intellectual version of the play Twelve
Angry Men. Gradually, through force of persistent argument and marshaling
of evidence, he brought his fellow commission members around to the
previously unthinkable view that both our national security and our
broader interest would be served by a volunteer military.”
Beyond Milton Friedman the economist, writes Summers, “...there
was Milton Friedman the public philosopher. Ask reformers in any one
of the countries behind what we used to call the Iron Curtain where
they learned to contemplate alternatives to Communism during the closed
era before the Berlin Wall fell, and they will often tell you about
reading Milton Friedman and realizing how different their world would
be.... Milton Friedman and I probably never voted the same way in any
election... I have my list of areas where I believe Mr. Friedman oversimplified
or was simply wrong. Nonetheless, like many others, I feel that I have
lost a hero — a man whose success demonstrates that great ideas
convincingly advanced can change the lives of people around the world.”
In an era when most of his fellow economists were advocating one
or another form of government control of the economy, Friedman became
an ardent crusader for capitalism and economic freedom. He did not
advocate capitalism because of sympathy for the rich. Friedman himself
was born in New York, the son of poor Jewish immigrants. His father
died when Milton was l5, leaving his mother with very little money
to pay for their son’s education. His
advocacy of capitalism came because in a society based upon free enterprise,
all citizens — both the rich and the poor, and the majority,
who were middle-class — would prosper. More important, freedom
could exist only when the state did not control the economic lives
of its citizens.
How sad that, instead of being proud of Milton Friedman's accomplishments,
these former colleagues at the University of Chicago seek to prevent
the establishment of an institute named for him. Hopefully, the university
will resist these efforts to impose a narrow liberal orthodoxy upon
a distinguished institution.
The Conservative Curmudgeon archives
The Conservative Curmudgeon is copyright © 2008
by the Fitzgerald Griffin Foundation, www.fgfBooks.com.
All rights reserved. Editors may use this column if this copyright information
is included.
Allan C. Brownfeld is the author of five books, the latest of which
is The Revolution Lobby (Council for Inter-American Security). He has
been a staff aide to a U.S. Vice President, Members of Congress, and
the U.S. Senate Internal Subcommittee.
He is associate editor of The Lincoln Reveiw and a contributing
editor to such publications as Human Events,
The St. Croix Review, and The Washington Report on Middle
East Affairs.
To subscribe, renew, or donate: click
here.